Note: Answers may be longer than I would deem sufficient on an exam. Some might vary slightly based on points of interest, examples, or personal experience. These suggested answers are designed to give you both the answer and a short explanation of why it is the answer.
Economic costs take into consideration accounting (monetary) costs as well as opportunity costs (what else a firm could be doing instead with its resources). Accounting costs are largely backward looking: what is the monetary value of a past decision made. Recall opportunity cost is forward looking–what is the next best use of my resources as I make a decision now, going forward.
Economic profits are total revenues minus total economic costs, whereas accounting profits only measure revenues minus accounting costs.
Economic cost is almost always larger than accounting costs, so economic profits are almost always smaller than accounting profits. A firm can thus be earning an accounting profit but operating at an economic loss (or normal economic profits of 0) – implying there are better (or equivalent), more value-creating uses of their resources than their current use.
As opportunity costs are never negative, a firm earning an economic profit must be earning an even larger accounting profit.
Profits are zero in the long run because entry and exit are free in competitive markets. Any firms earning positive (supernormal) profits in an industry will attract entrants, who want profits of their own. This will increase the supply and will continue until all profits are squeezed to zero (and then no more firms enter). Conversely, firms earning negative profits (loses) will exit the industry over the long run, decreasing the supply, and firms will continue to do this until losses fall back to zero. Thus, the stable equilibrium condition is that an industry tends to earn profits of zero, as any deviation would cause entry and exit until profits/losses get competed back to zero.
Firms that have rent-generating inputs see lower costs, and therefore higher profits. The problem is, these rent-generating inputs can be “poached” and enticed to work for other firms. This competition between firms pushes up prices for those rent-generating inputs. This raises the costs for those firms employing those inputs, in the form of higher salaries, higher lease prices, etc., whatever it takes to keep the input working for the firm and not a different firm. In equilibrium, rents rise until they push costs to equal revenues, and hence, profits to equal 0.
Show all work for calculations. You may lose points, even if correct, for missing work. Be sure to label graphs fully, if appropriate.
Output (hundreds) | Labor |
---|---|
0 | 0 |
1 | 1 |
2 | 3 |
3 | 6 |
4 | 11 |
5 | 20 |
First, recognize that fixed costs are $500, regardless of whether or not Frame de Art frames any artwork, they have to pay rent on their storefront. The only variable cost is paying wages to workers (at $300/worker).
Output (hundreds) | Labor | f | VC(q)=wl | C(q)=f+VC(q) | MC(q) | AC(q) |
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
0 | 0 | 500 | 0 | 500 | − | − |
1 | 1 | 500 | 300 | 800 | 300 | 800 |
2 | 3 | 500 | 900 | 1,400 | 600 | 700 |
3 | 6 | 500 | 1,800 | 2,300 | 900 | 600 |
4 | 11 | 500 | 3,300 | 3,800 | 1,500 | 950 |
5 | 20 | 500 | 6,000 | 6,500 | 2,700 | 1,300 |
Mike should use a small plant for 125 bikes. Even though both a small and a medium plant could produce 125, the small plant can do it cheaper (it’s AC is lower than the medium plant’s AC). Mike should use the medium plant to produce 150 bikes, because it offers a lower AC than the small plant for that range of output.
Mike should use a medium plant for 250 bikes. Even though both a medium and a large plant could produce 250, the medium plant can do it cheaper (it’s AC is lower than the large plant’s AC). Mike should use the large plant to produce 275 bikes, because it offers a lower AC than the medium plant for that range of output.
The long run average cost curve consists of the section of each short run average cost curve that is lower than that any other short run average cost curve that overlaps that range of output. It “envelopes” the lowest section of each short run average costs curve. It is shaded more heavily on the graph.
LRC(q)=164q3−6.25q2+725q
LRMC(q)=364q2−12.5q+725
First, we need to find LRAC(q).
LRAC(q)=LRC(q)q=164q3−6.25q2+725qq=164q2−6.25q+725
We know that LRAC(q) is minimized where it is equal to LRMC(q), so:
LRAC(q)=LRMC(q)Minimum of LRAC(q)164q2−6.25q+725=364q2−12.5q+725Plugging in Equations164q2−6.25q=364q2−12.5qSubtracting 725−6.25q=264q2−12.5qSubtracting 164q26.25q=264q2Adding 12.5q6.25=264qDividing by q200=q∗Multiplying by 642
Average cost is minimized at 200 bikes. This is also the logical minimum value according to the graph. Since this is a U-shaped curve:
It is not asked, but if you want to calculate what is the minimum average cost, plug in 200 to the average cost function:
LRAC(q)=16412−6.25y+725LRAC(200)=164(200)2−6.25(200)+725LRAC(200)=164(40,000)−1,250+725LRAC(200)=625−1,250+725LRAC(200)=$100
C(q)=2q2+3q+50MC(q)=4q+3
Fixed costs are where costs don’t change with output, so any term(s) where there is no variable q in them: 50. We could also see that if q=0:
C(q)=2q2+3q+50C(0)=2(0)2+3(0)+50C(0)=50
Variable costs change with output, so any term(s) with a variable q in them:
VC(q)=2q2+3q
AFC(q)=FCq=50q
AVC(q)=VC(q)q=2q2+3qq=2q+3
AC(q)=C(q)q=2q2+3q+50q=2q+3+50q
Alternatively, we know that:
AC(q)=AVC(q)+AFC(q)=(2q+3)+(50q)=2q+3+50q
The graph below visualizes all costs:
We know that a competitive firm earns no profits where p=AC(q). Since in competitive markets p=MR(q) and firms are always setting MR(q)=MC(q), we are looking for the quantity q∗ where:
AC(q)=MC(q)Minimum of AC2q+3+50q=4q+3Filling in equations2q+50q=4qSubtracting 32q2+50=4q2Multiplying by q50=2q2Subtracting 2q225=q2Dividing by 25=qSquare rooting
Average cost at an output of 5 is:
AC(q)=2q+3+50qAC(5)=2(5)+3+50(5)=10+3+10=$23
We know that a competitive firm shuts down where p<AVC(q), so let’s find the price where p=AVC(q). Since in competitive markets p=MR(q) and firms are always setting MR(q)=MC(q), we are looking for the quantity q where:
We know this happens where:
AVC(q)=MC(q)2q+3=4q+32q=4q0=2q0=q
This is is the quantity, now let’s plug in q=0 into either of these equations to find the actual price:
AVC(0)=2(0)+3AVC(0)=$3
The shut down price is $3.
The firm chooses q∗ such that:
MR(q)=MC(q)p=4q+3
The vertical intercept of $3 is the choke price, where the firm decides to not produce. This is because $3 is the minimum average variable cost, so any price lower than that would incur the firm’s shut down condition:
Firm's Short Run Inverse Supply={MC(q)if p≥AVCq=0if p<AVC={p=4q+3if p≥$3q=0if p<$3
The firm will only produce in the long run if it earns no losses, that is, if p≥AC(q):
Firm's Long Run Inverse Supply={MC(q)if p≥ACq=0if p<AC={p=4q+3if p≥$23q=0if p<$23
In the short run, even under losses, the firm will still produce so long as p>AVC, compare to our answer in part (h).
The long run equilibrium price must yield no profits (or else there would be entry or exit). Profit is 0 where p=AC. Since firms always set p=MC, it must be the case that AC=MC, which happens at the minimum of the average cost curve, and we saw the break-even price was $23.
The market price must be $23: any price higher would induce entry, any price lower would induce exit.
C(q)=100+4q2MC(q)=8q
Joe is in a perfectly competitive market, so he will prepare up to the quantity where p=MR(q)=MC(q).
p=MC(q)120=8q15=q∗
He will prepare 15 tax returns per day to maximize profits.
The following graph will help visualize all the parts of this question:
Profit is total revenues minus total costs:
π=pq−C(q)π=(120)(15)−(100+4q2)π=1800−(100+4(15)2)π=1800−1000π=$800
His profits are $800 (per day).
Alternatively, we could calculate profits as price minus average costs times quantity. First we would need to find average costs at q∗=15:
AC(q)=100q+4qAC(15)=10015+4(15)AC(15)≈6.67+60AC(15)≈66.67
Knowing this, we plug it into the formula for profits using price and average costs:
π=(p−AC(q∗))q∗π≈(120−66.67)15π≈(53.33)15π≈$800
A firm breaks even where its Average cost equals its marginal cost. We aren’t given average cost, so we first need to find it by taking total cost and dividing by quantity:
AC(q)=C(q)qAC(q)=100+4q2qAC(q)=100q+4q
Now we know that average cost is minimized where:
AC(q)=MC(q)100q+4q=8q100q=4q100=4q225=q25=q∗
We know the quantity but we need to find the price where the firm breaks even, so plugging this back into average cost:
AC(q)=100q+4qAC(5)=100(5)+4(5)AC(5)=20+20AC(5)=40
Joe will break even, and earn normal profits of 0 if the market price were $40 per tax return.
A firm shuts down in the short run when it can no longer cover its average variable costs. We know the minimum average variable cost happens when it is equal to marginal cost. Since we are not given it, we first need to find average variable costs.
AVC(q)=VC(q)qAVC(q)=4q2qAVC(q)=4q
Now we know AVC is minimized where:
AVC(q)=MC(q)4q=8qq=0
Average variable cost is minimized when Joe produces no output.
Let’s check and see what price has an output of 0, by using either the AVC(q) or MC(q) curves:
AVC(q)=4qAVC(0)=4(0)AVC(0)=$0
So Joe would shut down only when the price is less than $0 (which can’t happen). This happens when the AVC function is not a curve, but a straight line starting at the origin.